Wednesday, September 18, 2013

Encouraging Outward FDI
Many investor nations now have government-backed insurance programs to cover
major types of foreign investment risk. The types of risks insurable through these programs
include expropriation (nationalization), war losses, and the inability to transfer
profits home. Such programs are particularly useful in encouraging firms to undertake
investments in politically unstable countries.j" In addition, several advanced countries
also have special funds or banks that make government loans to firms wishing to invest
in developing countries. As a further incentive to encourage domestic firms to undertake
FDI, many countries have eliminated double taxation offoreign income (i.e.,
taxation of income in both the host country and the home country). Last, and perhaps
most significant, a number of investor countries (including the United States) h;;tve
used their political influence to persuade host countries to relax their restrictions on
inbound FDL For example, in response to direct U.S. pressure,Japan relaxed many
of its formal restrictions on inward FDI in the 1980s. Now, in response to further U.S.
pressure,Japan moved toward relaxing its informal barriers to inward FDL One beneficiary
of this trend has been Toys "R" Us, which, after five years of intensive lobbying
by company and U.S. government officials, opened its first retail stores inJapan
in December 1991. By 2000, Toys "R" Us had more than 150 stores inJapan, and its
Japanese operation, in which the company retained a controlling stake, had a listing
on the Japanese stock exchange.

Restricting Outward FDI
Virtually all investor countries, including the United States, have exercised some control
over outward FDI from time to time. One common policy has been to limit capital
outflows out of concern for the country's balance of payments. From the early
1960s until 1979, for example, Great Britain had exchange-control regulations that
limited the amount of capital a firm could take out of the country. Although the main
ntentof such policies was to improve the British balance of payments, an important
secondary intent was to make it more difficult for British firms to undertake FDI.
In addition, countries have occasionally manipulated tax rules to try to encourage
their firms to invest at home. The objective behind such policies is to create jobs at
home rather than in other nations. At one time these policies were also adopted by
Great Britain. The British advanced corporation tax system taxed British companies'
foreign earnings at a higher rate than their domestic earnings. This tax code created
an incentive for British companies to invest at home.
Finally, countries sometimes prohibit firms from investing in certain countries for
political reasons. Such restrictions can be formal or informal. For example, formal
rules prohibited U.S. firms from investing in countries such as Cuba, Libya, and Iran,
whose political ideology and actions are judged to be contrary to U.S. interests. Similarly,
during the 1980s, informal pressure was applied to dissuade U.S. firms from investing
in South Africa. In this case, the objective was to pressure South Africa to
change its apartheid laws, which occurred during the early 1990s. Thus, this policy
was successful.
HOST-COUNTRY POLICIES
Host countries adopt policies designed both to restrict and to encourage inward FDI.
As noted earlier in this chapter, political ideology has determined the type and scope
of these policies in the past. In the last decade of the 20th century, many countries
moved quickly away from adhering to some version of the radical stance and prohibiting
much FDI and toward a combination of free market objectives and pragmatic
nationalism.
Encouraging Inward FDI
It is .infTPa".i.r.>gJy commas: for govemments to offer incentives to foreign firms to invest
in their countries. Such incentives take many forms, but the most common are
tax concessions, low-interest loans, and grants or subsidies. Incentives are motivated
by a desire to gain from the resource-transfer and employment effects of FDI. They
are also motivated by a desire to capture FDI away from other potential host countries.
For example, in the mid-1990s the governments of Great Britain and France
competed with each other on the incentives they offered Toyota to invest in their respective
countries. In the United States, state governments often compete with each
other to attract FDI. For example, Kentucky offered Toyota an incentive package
worth $112 million to persuade it to build its U.S. automobile assembly plants there.
The package included tax breaks, new state spending on infrastructure, and lowinterest
loans.t"
Restricting Inward FDI
Host governments use a wide range of controls to restrict FDI in one way or another.
The two most common are ownership restraints and performance rf'-9JJir.t'.we.>;ltu~.
OwnershIp restraints can take several forms. In some countries, foreign companies are
excluded from specific fields. For example, they are excluded from tobacco and mining
in Sweden and from the development of certain natural resources in Brazil, Finland,
and Morocco. In other industries, foreign ownership may be permitted although
a significant proportion of the equity of the subsidiary must be owned by local investors.
For example, foreign ownership is restricted to 25 percent or less of an airline
in the United States.
Foreign firms are often excluded from certain sectors on the grounds of national security
or competition. Particularly in less developed countries, the belief seems to be
that local firms might not be able to develop unless foreign competition is restricted
by a combination of import tariffs and FDI controls. This is really a variant of the infant
industry argument discussed in Chapter 5.
Also, ownership restraints seem to be based on a belief that local owners can help
to maximize the resource-transfer and employment benefits ofFDI for the host country.
Until the early 1980s, theJapanese government prohibited most FDI but allowed
joint ventures betweenJapanese firms and foreign MNEs if the MNE had a valuable
technology. The Japanese government clearly believed such an arrangement would
speed up the subsequent diffusion of the MNE's valuable technology throughout the
Japanese economy.
Performance requirements can also take several forms. Performance requirements
are controls over the behavior of the MNE's local subsidiary. The most common performance
requirements are related to local content, exports, technology transfer, and
local participation in top management. As with certain ownership restrictions, the
logic underlying performance requirements is that such rules help to maximize the
benefits and minimize the costs of FDI for the host country. Virtually all countries employ
some form of performance requirements when it suits their objectives. However,
performance requirements tend to be more common in less developed countries than
in advanced industrialized nations. For example, one study found that some 30 percent
of the affiliates of U.S. MNEs in less developed countries were subject to performance
requirements, while only 6 percent of the affiliates in advanced countries were
faced with such requirementsY


0 Comments:

Post a Comment

<< Home

Gong Xi Fa Cai


From SmartYInvestor